Archive

Author Archive

The European Court of Justice Resoundingly Rejects Google’s Final Appeal

September 10th, 2024 No comments

London, 10 September 2024 – Statement by Shivaun Raff, CEO and Co-Founder of Foundem, the original and lead Complainant in the European Commission’s Google Search (Comparison Shopping) investigation, and an Intervener in Google’s Appeals of the EC’s June 2017 Prohibition Decision to the General Court and European Court of Justice:

We welcome today’s judgment, which upholds the Commission’s June 2017 Prohibition Decision.

However, it is now well past time for the Commission to bring an end to Google’s anti-competitive conduct—either by finally enforcing the equal treatment remedy mandated by the Prohibition Decision, or by enforcing the equivalent equal treatment obligation under Article 6.5 of the DMA.[1]

As the company that first brought these matters to the attention of regulators on both sides of the Atlantic, it is disheartening to note that, in the fifteen years since our competition complaint and seven years since the Prohibition Decision that upheld it, Google has done nothing to end or curtail its unlawful practices.

Through a toxic combination of anti-competitive penalties and a CSS Auction introduced in the guise of a remedy,[2] Google has now all but eradicated comparison shopping from its search results. Instead of being a click away from a comprehensive survey of the market for their chosen product, Google’s users are now presented with a small number of pay-for-placement ads, selected for their ability to maximise Google’s profits not their ability to deliver the lowest prices for consumers.

For a detailed timeline of the events leading up to and during the EC’s antitrust investigation, Prohibition Decision and subsequent appeals, see our Timeline on searchneutrality.org.

Categories: Google Tags:

Foundem’s Analysis of the DMA (and its Possible Implications for Google)

November 23rd, 2022 No comments

Here is our Overview and Analysis of the DMA:  Foundem_DMA_Analysis.pdf.

While this paper covers all aspects of the Digital Markets Act, our twelve-years (and counting) involvement in the Google Search (Comparison Shopping) case means that our analysis has a particular emphasis on the DMAs implications for Google’s ongoing search manipulation practices.

Categories: Foundem, Google, Search Neutrality Tags:

Our Statement Welcoming Today’s Judgment

November 10th, 2021 No comments

We welcome today’s General Court judgment, which comprehensively upholds the Commission’s June 2017 Google Search (Comparison Shopping) Prohibition Decision.

While we welcome today’s judgment, it does not undo the considerable consumer[1] and anti-competitive harm caused by more than a decade of Google’s insidious search manipulation practices. Nor will it restore competition to the beleaguered comparison shopping market.[2] That will require the European Commission to stop procrastinating and finally enforce the equal-treatment remedy it mandated in its Prohibition Decision.

It has now been twelve years since we submitted the Competition Complaint that triggered the EC’s investigation, and four years since the Prohibition Decision upheld our complaint and declared that Google had just 90 days to remedy its illegal conduct or face substantial additional fines. Yet, to date, Google has done nothing to end or mitigate its unlawful conduct.

Former Competition Commissioner Almunia spent years pursuing minor cosmetic tweaks to a positively harmful, worse than doing nothing, auction-based “remedy” proposal.[3] And Commissioner Vestager has now spent four years doing much the same.[4]  The Commission continues to “monitor” the brazenly non-compliant[5] CSS Auction Google introduced in the guise of a Compliance Mechanism in September 2017.

The main difference between the current CSS auction (masquerading as a “compliance mechanism”) and Google’s previous CSS auctions (masquerading as “remedy” proposals), is that this time Google’s own CSS is also participating in the auction. But Google’s participation in the auction isn’t real. In stark contrast to rival CSSs who are compelled to bid away the vast majority of any anticipated profit, Google’s own bids are just meaningless internal accounting that cost it nothing.[6]

If a thief demands your wallet, would you be placated if he reassured you that he was also intending to rob himself? Of course not. Because you instinctively understand that this is an empty promise. A thief cannot meaningfully rob himself any more than Google’s CSS can meaningfully participate in a Google auction. As Google’s financial accounts would readily confirm, any “cost” attributed to a Google bid is cancelled out by the corresponding and equal “credit” generated by that same bid. Google’s CSS could literally bid ten million euros per click and it wouldn’t cost Google Inc. a cent. Just as our imaginary thief’s meaningless promise to also rob himself doesn’t become meaningful if he follows through with the charade by handing himself his own wallet before putting it back in his own pocket.

We used to say that it would be difficult to imagine an antitrust case with more at stake than the Google Search case. And despite recent developments, which have shown how the conduct of certain social media companies can pose a threat to the very fabric of society, it is still difficult to imagine a case where the stakes for consumers, businesses, and innovation could be any higher. As the gateway to the Internet, Google plays a decisive role in determining what most of us read, use, and purchase online. The importance of ending Google’s ability to manipulate this unprecedented power to its own anti-competitive ends cannot be overstated.

Today’s judgment provides the Commission with a firm basis to now enforce its June 2017 Prohibition Decision—not just for the beleaguered comparison shopping market directly addressed by the Decision, but also for the travel, local, jobs and other vertical search markets for which this Decision sets a precedent.

For the full timeline of significant events before, during, and after the EC, FTC, and DOJ Google antitrust investigations, please see our Timeline.

Categories: Google Tags:

Google’s Call for Enforcement Action?

September 18th, 2020 No comments

We were surprised by Director General Guersent’s recent comments on the Google Search (Comparison Shopping) case, claiming to have seen “positive developments” in Google’s CSS Auction “remedy”.[1]

As we, and others, have demonstrated (for example, here, here, and here), Google’s CSS Auction is the polar opposite of the equal treatment remedy mandated by the EC’s June 2017 Prohibition Decision.  In fact, as we have also demonstrated (for example, here), Google’s CSS Auction is just a thinly-veiled continuation of the same abuse already identified by the Decision. Google’s CSS Auction recreates Google’s anti-competitive Shopping Units under another name and leaves Google’s anticompetitively-applied penalty algorithms in place and unaltered.

Crucially, since the February Appeal Hearing in Luxembourg, we can now add Google itself to the long list of parties that wholeheartedly agree with this damning assessment. At the Hearing, Google confirmed from the top-down what our December 2018 presentation had demonstrated from the bottom-up.

For a variety of reasons (which we will explain at a later date), it suited Google to point out that the options available to rival CSSs during the abuse were “identical to those currently available to rival comparison shopping services[2] today, through Google’s CSS Auction. For example, on Day 1 of the Hearing, Google claimed that since 2013 “[rival CSSs] in fact could place product ads in Shopping Units based on the same conditions that apply to product ads from Google’s CSS”.  But, as Google went on to explain, this ability for rival CSSs to place ads in Shopping Units came at an existential price. As Google put it: “[rival CSSs] had two options to place product ads in Shopping Units…The first option was for [rival CSSs] to place product ads that linked to pages on their own site that had buy functionality…The second option was for the [rival CSSs] to place product ads that link to the pages of their advertising partners.”  That is, to participate in Shopping Units, rival CSSs would have had to abandon their CSS functionality to become either a merchant (with “buy functionality”) or an advertising agency (placing “ads that link to the pages of their advertising partners”).

Crucially, by Google’s own admission, these two untenable options are exactly the same untenable options that Google’s CSS Auction now provides under the guise of a “remedy”.  Indeed, this explains the recent proliferation of so-called “fake CSSs”—advertising agencies that Google has approached and financially incentivised to pose as CSSs and thereby create the illusion of a functioning remedy.[3]

This belated confession by Google should put an end to the EC’s procrastination. It is well past time for the EC to enforce its Decision and issue non-compliance proceedings against Google’s anti-competitive and brazenly non-compliant CSS Auction. This enforcement action would now be supported by (a) the overwhelming evidence from complainants and market-participants, (b) the fundamental findings of the EC’s Prohibition Decision, and (c) Google’s own explicit admissions during the Appeal Hearing that its purported “remedy” offers rival CSSs nothing that wasn’t already available under Google’s previous abusive conduct. As Google put it: “this is what Google already allowed [rival CSSs] to do before the Decision.”[4]

Categories: Google Tags:

Google’s CSS Auction: Different Name, Same Illegal Conduct

November 1st, 2019 No comments

Our November 3rd 2009 Competition Complaint triggered the EC’s and US FTC’s antitrust investigations into Google’s search manipulation practices.  As we approach the 10-year anniversary of our Complaint, and with Commissioner Vestager set to embark on a welcome second consecutive term as Competition Commissioner, it seems like a good time to reflect on what has been achieved, and, more importantly, what remains to be achieved.

Having issued three landmark Prohibition Decisions against Google during her first term (totalling nearly $10 billion in fines), it is now critical that Commissioner Vestager uses her second term to enforce those Decisions—holding Google to effective and compliant remedies that restore the level playing field Google has spent the last decade quietly tilting in its favour.

Our November 2017 and April 2018 online presentations demonstrated that Google’s CSS Auction, which Google introduced as a “Compliance Mechanism”, falls far short of the equal treatment standard mandated by the EC’s June 2017 Prohibition Decision.  Today, we are publishing a presentation that demonstrates that this auction is, in fact, a thinly-veiled continuation of exactly the same anti-competitive conduct already defined and prohibited by the Decision:

View Slideshow

Google could have interpreted the Commission’s June 2017 demand for equal treatment within its search result pages as a call for a return to the relevance-based search results Google built its reputation and monopoly on.  After all, that is what most of Google’s users wrongly assume they are still getting when they use Google.  But, instead, Google has thumbed its nose at both the Commission and its own users by misinterpreting the Commission’s call for equal access to relevance-based search results as a demand for unequal, and positively harmful, access to pay-for-placement advertisements.

And, this isn’t the first time Google has tried this ruse.  Google’s three previous auction-based “remedy” proposals were all resoundingly rejected under Commissioner Almunia, precisely because they were auction-based.[1]  As we explained in our earlier presentations, the primary difference between Google’s current auction-based offering and its three previous versions is that, in the current version, Google’s own service also “participates” in the auction.  But this participation is a facade: in stark contrast to rivals’ bids, which deprive rivals of nearly all of their profits (and, with it, their ability and incentive to innovate and grow), Google’s own “bids” cost Google nothing.  As we explained, that’s because Google’s bids aren’t real. They are, literally and figuratively, monopoly money—meaningless internal accounting, where every transaction recorded as a “cost” has an equal and corresponding “credit”.

Google’s CSS Auction presents users with pay-for-placement advertisements from the highest bidders, instead of the relevance-based search results they almost certainly came to Google for. Unsurprisingly, whenever relevance-based search results are replaced with ads—where the amount advertisers are willing to pay is often a decisive factor in determining which ads are shown—this inevitably leads to users paying higher prices for products and services than they would otherwise.[2]

As mentioned above, the presentation we are publishing today demonstrates that Google’s CSS Auction is not only the polar opposite of equal treatment, it is, in fact, a direct continuation of the same anti-competitive conduct already identified and prohibited by the EC’s June 2017 Decision.

As our presentation explains, in February 2013, Google introduced a fundamental change to the self-preferencing half of the anti-competitive search manipulation practices the EC and FTC were actively investigating.  This change (from prominently positioned links to Google’s CSS to prominently positioned pay-for-placement ads lifted directly from Google’s CSS) made no difference to the traffic Google was anti-competitively diverting away from competing services, but it did make a difference to how and where that traffic was diverted.

Google’s adoption of a pay-for-placement model represented a substantial departure from several of Google’s founding principles, including the “clear, large wall between the objective search results and the ads”,[3] and the promise that, “at Google, search results cannot be bought or paid for”.[4]  Indeed, this change prompted headlines such as “How Evil Are Google’s New Paid Shopping Search Results?”[5] and “Google product search results get a commercial bias”.[6]

Google didn’t just make this change during the EC’s investigation; it did so in the midst of what were supposed to be good faith settlement negotiations.  This is particularly troubling, because we now know that one of the ways Google persuaded the EC to explore the possibility of a settlement in the first place was by dangling a remedy proposal that guaranteed deep-links to rival services alongside Google’s own, with no mention or hint of any payment or auction. On the contrary, Google’s June 2012 written outline of this proposal made clear that it would select and place three rival services based solely on their algorithmically determined relevance to the user’s search query. For example, the following is an extract from Google’s June 2012 proposal[7] (which, to the best of our knowledge, has not previously been publicly discussed):

“Google proposes to display up to three, algorithmically selected links to rival “vertical” search sites within Google’s Product and Local Universal Results…These links will lead, to the extent possible, directly to result pages of the alternative vertical search site for the query that the user entered on Google…for each relevant query, Google will algorithmically select for display three qualifying sites based on their Web Search rank for that query…

Because rival sites will be selected algorithmically different sites can appear for different types of queries…and new sites may surface as they gain in relevance.”

It seems that Google’s February 2013 transition to a pay-for-placement model might have been the sole basis for the bait-and-switch Google then pulled; by the time Google’s official proposals were submitted in May 2013, the promised links to rival services had morphed from helpful, relevance-based search results, into positively harmful, pay-for-placement ads via an auction.

Not only did this transition pave the way for several years of futile negotiations around variations on an auction-based mechanism that never had any prospect of delivering a viable remedy, it also presented the Commission with a challenge:  How to deal with this change in Google’s anti-competitive conduct—from the straightforward traffic-diversion of Product Universals and penalties, to the less straightforward, but even more harmful, traffic-and-revenue-diversion of Shopping Units and penalties?

As we explain in our presentation, the solution was to follow the money.  The finding at paragraph 630 of the Prohibition Decision allows Google’s transition from link-based traffic-diversion to ad-based revenue-and-traffic-diversion to be both identified and empirically quantified.  And, it is this same pivotal finding that allows us to demonstrate that Google’s so-called “Compliance Mechanism” is an empirically quantifiable continuation of exactly the same illegal conduct already identified by the Decision.

Finally, with U.S. regulators now launching fresh probes into Google’s anti-competitive practices, it is worth noting that Google made exactly the same transition from traffic-diverting Product Universals to traffic-and-revenue-diverting Shopping Units in the U.S. in October 2012.  As U.S. regulators look to address the immense escalation in consumer and competitive harm caused by this transition, they will need to follow the EC’s lead.  We hope that our presentation, which explains the crucial empirical relationship between the traffic diverted by Product Universals and the traffic/revenue diverted by Shopping Units, might be of some assistance in this regard.

 


[1] For example, see here, here, and here.       `

[3] Sergey Brin, April 2004 Interview with Playboy Magazine

[4] Ibid.

[5] Forbes, May 31 2012

[6] Venture Beat, May 31 2012

[7] Extracts from Google’s June 30 2012, Annex 1 – Discussion Paper Submitted by Google on The Preliminary Concerns Identified by the EC and Google’s Proposed Solution

Categories: Google Tags:

Open Letter to Commissioner Vestager from 14 European CSSs

November 22nd, 2018 No comments

The following open letter was sent to Commissioner Vestager today, signed by 14 European comparison shopping services (PDF):

 

Ms Margrethe Vestager
Commissioner for Competition
European Commission
Rue de la Loi
B – 1049 Brussels

22 November 2018

Dear Commissioner Vestager,

RE: AT.39740 – Google Search (Comparison Shopping)

We are writing to you as leading European comparison shopping services (CSSs) to express our collective view that Google’s “compliance mechanism” in the Google Search (Comparison Shopping) case does not comply with the European Commission’s June 2017 Prohibition Decision. It has now been more than a year since Google introduced its auction-based “remedy”, and the harm to competition, consumers and innovation caused by Google’s illegal conduct has continued unabated. We therefore respectfully urge you to commence non-compliance proceedings against Google.

As explained in this April 2018 presentation[1], an auction-based mechanism cannot comply with the equal treatment standard set out in the Prohibition Decision:

- While rivals are compelled to bid away the vast majority of their profits, Google Shopping’s bids cost it nothing—its bids are just meaningless internal accounting, paid from one Google pocket into another.

- Google’s commitment to a notional 20% “profit” margin imposes an artificial limit on Google Shopping’s otherwise unlimited ability to outbid its rivals—but this is equally meaningless. While this promise can create a narrow opening for competing CSSs to sometimes bid their way onto the page, it does nothing to address the inescapable and transformative inequality between bids that cost Google nothing and bids that cost competitors their incentive and ability to innovate and grow.

- In common with Google’s three previous auction-based proposals (which were all resoundingly rejected under Commissioner Almunia), the visibility of rivals’ links is also meaningless. As long as placement is determined by auction rather than relevance, it makes little material difference whether competitors occupy none, some, or even all of the available slots. In all cases, Google is the main beneficiary of any profits derived from these entries, and consumers are the main losers (see below).

If there has ever been any doubt that Google’s auction-based “remedy” is neither compliant nor effective, recent developments should have finally put this to rest.

The harsh reality is that a pay-for-placement auction is fundamentally incompatible with the concept of comparison shopping (or, indeed, any other form of vertical search).   As a result, few rivals have chosen to participate in Google’s CSS auction and, when they have, genuine CSSs that employ a consumer-friendly paid-inclusion model have struggled to outbid services like Google Shopping that, since 2013, employ a consumer-unfriendly pay-for-placement model.

Presumably, realising that it will never be possible to populate its new auction with enough genuine comparison shopping services to create even the veneer of a functioning remedy, Google has now set about populating it with fake ones instead[2]: Google has recently begun reaching out to Google Shopping Ad Agencies to encourage and incentivise them to pose as CSSs.

In exchange for a hefty rebate and official Google Certified CSS Partner status (a status granted despite offering no comparison shopping functionality of any kind), these Ad Agencies now bypass the Google Shopping auction and bid instead for placement in Google’s new, ostensibly-CSS-only auction.  In other words, where these Ad Agencies used to feed their merchants’ ad inventories into Google Shopping, they now feed these same ad inventories directly into Google’s CSS auction instead.  Crucially, Google is not doing this because it is confused about the many important differences between an Ad Agency and a comparison shopping service; it is doing it to circumvent the Commission’s Prohibition Decision, by simply recreating Google Shopping under a different name and then continuing to illegally favour it in exactly the same way as before.

The points outlined above should be more than sufficient grounds for the Commission to reject Google’s proposed “remedy” and commence non-compliance proceedings. But, the problems with Google’s auction-based mechanism go well beyond non-compliance: far from restoring a thriving comparison shopping market, Google’s CSS auction all but eradicates it.  Pay-for-placement advertisements are the antithesis of relevance-based search results, and, because users who click on them are taken directly to merchants rather than to the CSSs that feature them, there is no opportunity for CSSs or users to add or derive value from the process.

Indeed, Google’s new auction offers nothing of value to consumers.  On the contrary, instead of relevance-based search results, which—absent Google’s illegal conduct—would naturally contain an appropriate blend of merchants, CSSs, manufacturer sites and so on, users are presented with a selection of advertisements for specific products from specific merchants.  These are not the best products, the best merchants, or the best prices; they are whatever specific products and merchants are likely to earn Google the most profit from a click. Not only do Google’s users inevitably end up paying higher prices for products than they need to, they are often left completely unaware that comparison shopping services even exist—a problem exacerbated by Google’s failure to address the anti-competitive demotion/penalty half of its illegal conduct.

We respectfully urge the Commission to enforce its Prohibition Decision by rejecting Google’s non-compliant “compliance mechanism” and demanding an effective remedy that adheres to the principle of equal treatment set out in the Decision.

Yours sincerely,

Frédéric Lambert,
Founder and CEO, Acheter-moins-cher.com

Philipp Schrader,
CEO, Comparado (Preis.de)

Shivaun Raff and Adam Raff,
CEOs and Co-Founders, Foundem

Dr. Albrecht von Sonntag and Dr. Philipp-Christopher Peitsch,
CEOs, Idealo

Paulo Pimenta,
CEO, KuantoKusta

Michael Röcker,
CEO, LionsHome

Nicklas Storåkers,
CEO, PriceRunner

Peter Greberg,
CEO, Prisjakt / PriceSpy

Doug Scott and Alex Major,
Founder and CEO, RedBrain.com

Bernd Vermaaten,
CEO, Solute (Billiger.de)

Nicolas Le Borgne
CEO, StyleLounge

Ben Kerkhof,
CEO, Vergelijk (Compare Group)

Dr. Johannes Kotte and Robert Maier,
CEOs, Visual Meta (Ladenzeile / ShopAlike)

James Cunningham,
CEO and Co-founder, Yroo

 

Categories: Google Tags:

Decoding Google’s Behind-the-Scenes “Remedy” Manoeuvres

July 11th, 2018 No comments

Today, we are publishing our recent submission to the European Commission, which outlines some of Google’s latest behind-the-scenes “remedy” manoeuvres in the Google Search (Comparison Shopping) case and analyses their chilling implications.

Categories: Google Tags:

Debunking Google’s Blatantly Non-Compliant Remedy

April 18th, 2018 No comments

Today, we published our latest (and hopefully final!) interactive take-down of Google’s hopelessly ineffective and blatantly non-compliant “remedy” proposal.

This time around we take a more empirical approach, and directly address what we now believe to be the primary source of confusion: Google’s reassuring-sounding but effectively meaningless commitment to run Google Shopping at a notional “profit”.

Stripping away this confusion reveals that Google’s latest auction-based proposal is essentially the same as its previous, resoundingly rejected, auction-based proposals.

Categories: Google Tags:

An Open Letter to Commissioner Vestager

February 28th, 2018 No comments

The following open letter was sent to Commissioner Vestager today, signed by 19 companies and associations from across the comparison shopping, travel search, local search, digital mapping, and publishing sectors (PDF):

 

Ms Margrethe Vestager
Commissioner for Competition
European Commission
Rue de la Loi
B – 1049 Brussels
 
28 February 2018
 

Dear Commissioner Vestager,

RE: AT.39740 – Google Search (Comparison Shopping)

We are writing to express our common views on the European Commission’s ongoing monitoring of Google’s compliance with the Google Search Prohibition Decision.  Google’s current remedy proposal has been in operation for more than four months, and the harm to competition, consumers and innovation caused by the infringement established by the Decision has continued unabated.

In our view, Google’s current remedy proposal is no better than Google’s Commitment proposals under Commissioner Almunia, and in some ways may be worse.

Google’s remedy proposal is, on its face, non-compliant with the Prohibition Decision for at least three reasons:

- first, without full ownership unbundling (structural separation), Google Shopping’s participation in the auction is essentially meaningless;

- second, without explicit measures to prevent it, any fully- or over-subscribed auction inevitably leads to competing services being charged a fee that has the equivalent object or effect as the infringement established by the Decision; and

- third, the aggregation of rich product ads (derived from product feeds or their equivalent) in itself constitutes a comparison shopping service which Google is favouring in its general search results. Note that this remains true with or without the participation of Google Shopping.

And of course, the resultant wholesale replacement of relevance-based search results with pay-for-placement ads has terrible consequences for consumers.

Moreover, Google’s current remedy proposal does nothing to address the demotion half of Google’s illegal Conduct—the penalty algorithms, such as Panda, that are prone to demoting competing services.

It would be highly damaging to competition and consumers should the Commission attempt to resolve its ongoing investigations into Google’s similar anti-competitive conduct in other verticals with a Commitments Decision that is based on the same or similar ineffective “remedy”.

We respectfully urge the Commission to reject Google’s current remedy proposal and to hold Google to an effective remedy that complies with the principles of equal treatment set out in the Prohibition Decision.

We continue to be ready to provide the Commission with detailed feedback on any proposed remedy, including on Google’s first post-implementation report. We believe that our respective expertise might be critical to assess whether a remedy effectively puts an end to Google’s abuse of dominance.

Yours sincerely,

Frédéric Lambert,
Founder and General Manager, Acheter-moins-cher.com

Helmut Verdenhalven,
Head of Media Policy, BDZV (Federation of German Newspaper Publishers)

Sylvie Fodor,
Executive Director, CEPIC (Centre of the Picture Industry)

Philipp Schrader,
CEO, Comparado

Christoph Klenner,
Secretary General, ETTSA (European Technology & Travel Services Association)

Dr. h.c. Hans Biermann,
Chief Executive Officer, Euro-Cities

Thomas Vinje,
Legal Counsel and Spokesman, FairSearch

Shivaun Raff,
CEO and Co-founder, Foundem

Michael Weber,
Owner, Hot-Map.com

Tim Cowen,
Legal Counsel, ICOMP (Initiative for a Competitive Online Marketplace)

Dr. Albrecht von Sonntag and Dr. Philipp-Christopher Peitsch,
CEOs, Idealo

Eric Leandri,
President, OIP (Open Internet Project)

Kate Sutton,
Director, Streetmap.eu Ltd

Dr. Wolfgang Sander-Beuermann,
CEO, SUMA-EV

Bastien Duclaux,
CEO and Co-founder, Twenga

Prof. Dr. Christoph Fiedler,
Executive Director for European and Media Policy, VDZ (Association of German Magazine Publishers)

Ben Kerkhof,
CEO, Vergelijk (Compare Group)

Robert Maier,
Founder and CEO, Visual Meta

James Cunningham,
CEO and Co-founder, Yroo
 
 

 

Categories: Google Tags:

Why a Pay-For-Placement Auction Isn’t Equal Treatment – Part 2

November 7th, 2017 No comments

Following on from our September 2017 initial thoughts on Google’s proposed auction-based “remedy”, our latest presentation explains why the proposed functional separation of Google Shopping is essentially meaningless within the context of a pay-for-placement auction.

We also explore the various options that will be open to Google if, or more accurately when, the Commission informs Google that its current “remedy” proposal is not compliant with the required equal-treatment standard.

Click on the screenshot below to open the interactive presentation.

View Slideshow

Categories: Google Tags: